People have been enjoying my reposts from my old blog, so I’ll keep doing them occasionally. I was a much more acerbic, combative blogger a decade ago, probably due to the residual angst from grad school. Occasionally I unloaded on the titans of the economics profession — not that they noticed my existence, but it was still fun. This post is one of those.
The background here is that in 2012, Daron Acemoglu, James Robinson, and Thierry Verdier came out with a paper about the different “varieties of capitalism”. The basic idea was that Scandinavia’s more safety net discouraged entrepreneurship, while America’s relative lack of government support forced people to be risk-takers, and that this explained America’s greater rate of innovation. This is the kind of theory economists tend to like, because it emphasizes tradeoffs, and because it tells a story that allows economists to place themselves in the political center, charting the optimal middle path between the kind-hearted Democrats who want to give out free stuff and the exacting Republicans who want to force people to work for their supper. But other economists and bloggers immediately started noting problems with the thesis — most importantly, the fact that the Nordic countries are generally more innovative than the U.S. by many measures. Those countries are small, so you don’t hear about their innovations as much, but they really punch above their weight. Acemoglu et al. were trying to explain a “fact” that didn’t really exist.
That’s not just an academic “gotcha” — it really calls into question our whole model of why and how people become entrepreneurs. There’s one mental model that it’s all about effort — that entrepreneurs burn the midnight oil to get ahead, while placid normies go home at 5 and watch TV. In fact, differing effort is what drives the result in Acemoglu et al.’s paper. According to this view of the world, you can basically terrorize people into becoming entrepreneurs, by creating a world where failure is so horrifying that people will just do anything to escape it. That might sound preposterous, but there are plenty of stories of billionaires who grew up poor and resolved to get out of poverty any way they can.
But there’s another view of entrepreneurship, which is that it’s all about risk. Lots of people work incredibly hard, but most of them aren’t working at anything that has a chance of making them a billionaire — just look at ER doctors, or plenty of regular workers in Japan. The real thing that distinguishes entrepreneurs is that they take a lot of risk.
But the same risk looms larger to some people than others. If you’re a working-class person who has to risk utter financial ruin to start a business, you’re probably not going to do it. But if you’re a scion of a wealthy family, or if you have a high-paying Google job that you know you can go back to, failing isn’t going to ruin you. And if failing isn’t going to ruin you, why not take the plunge and go for the glory?
If what makes people become entrepreneurs is willingness to accept risk, then there may not be such a tradeoff between “cuddly” and “cutthroat” capitalism. In fact, a stronger safety net could actually encourage business formation, because it means that failure is less personally devastating. And in fact there are some studies that suggest this is true.
So this is really something for people in the tech industry, and especially venture capitalists, to think about. How do we get more entrepreneurs? Do we make the world more dangerous, as the advocates of “cutthroat capitalism” recommend? Or do we make it safer, so that people feel empowered to take more risks? When should people be driven by threats, and when should they be encouraged and supported?
Anyway, here’s my original blog post from 2012, where I argued that the top economists were thinking about it all wrong.
Daron Acemoglu and James Robinson have a paper out (with Thierry Verdier) about different "flavors" of capitalism and how these flavors could affect innovation. Specifically, they compare the "cuddly" capitalism of Europe to the "cutthroat" capitalism of America. First they make a simple mathematical model to show how more socialist "cuddly" countries like Sweden can act as parasites, leeching off of the innovations produced by the freewheeling "cutthroat" nations. Then they "test" their model by showing that the U.S. patents more stuff than Scandinavian countries.
This paper drew criticism from a number of bloggers. For example, here Lane Kenworthy asked: 1. What about alternate measures of innovation in which Scandinavian countries score close to the U.S.?, and 2. Wasn't the U.S. more "cuddly" back in the 70s, and weren't we just as innovative back then? And here, Matt Yglesias alleged that patents are a crummy measure of innovation.
Acemoglu and Robinson then defended themselves on their blog. After suggesting that criticism of their paper was motivated by politics (buncha commie bloggers!), Acemoglu and Robinson discuss what they believe to be the differing roles of blogs and academic research:
[There is a] divide between what the academic research in economics does — or is supposed to do — and the general commentary on economics in newspapers or in the blogosphere. When one writes a blog, a newspaper column or a general commentary on economic and policy matters, this often distills well-understood and broadly-accepted notions in economics and draws its implications for a particular topic. In original academic research (especially theoretical research), the point is not so much to apply already accepted notions in a slightly different context or draw their implications for recent policy debates, but to draw new parallels between apparently disparate topics or propositions, and potentially ask new questions in a way that changes some part of an academic debate. For this reason, simplified models that lead to “counterintuitive” (read unexpected) conclusions are particularly valuable; they sometimes make both the writer and the reader think about the problem in a total of different manner (of course the qualifier “sometimes” is important here; sometimes they just fall flat on their face).
Well, first of all, I disagree with the idea that counterintuitiveness is inherently good when evaluating academic research; growing up, I argued this point at length with my dad, who is a cognitive psychologist. But this is neither the time nor the place for that argument.
Instead, I want to make two points.
First, I want to point out that Acemoglu and Robinson's theoretical result is not very counterintuitive. The notion that there is a tradeoff between innovation and redistribution is quite a commonly-held belief. In Acemoglu and Robinson's theoretical model, this idea is a built-in assumption; is is not the result of the model, it is the model's starting point. To see this, just check out Section 2.2 on "Reward Structures". The authors assume that the reward to entrepreneurship (entrepreneurs are the same as innovators in their model) depends on the degree to which a country lets winners win and lets losers lose. The entrepreneurs decide how much effort to put out - if they try harder, they have a bigger chance of succeeding.
To my knowledge - and if I am wrong, please correct me! - this reward structure and this "return to effort", are not taken from any microeconomic study of entrepreneurial behavior; they are just something the authors wrote down.
Why did they write them down? A cynic would say: "Because these assumptions made the model work out the way the authors wanted it to", but I am not such a cynic. Instead, it seems to me that they wrote down these assumptions because they were intuitively plausible. It makes intuitive sense that the bigger the risk from losing, the more people will try hard not to end up being losers. And it makes intuitive sense that the harder someone tries, the better they do.
Given these assumptions, the result of the model is not hard to predict - when you let losers lose and winners win, innovators try harder. Not exactly a shocker, given the assumptions.
So is this model counterintuitive? I argue: No. Instead, it is intuitive. It seems to have been built using intuition, and its results confirm commonly-held beliefs about the difference between "cutthroat" and "cuddly" capitalism. So I don't think it makes much sense for Acemoglu and Robinson to defend their research from the bloggers by saying that the purpose of academic research is to be counterintuitive.
OK, time for my second point. Mark Thoma wondered why Acemoglu, Robinson, and Verdier get the result they get. Isn't it true that entrepreneurs have to take a lot of risk? And doesn't that mean that social insurance, which reduces risk, should encourage entrepreneurs to take more risk, not less? How is it that Acemoglu et al.'s model avoids this effect?
Here is the answer: it's built into the math. The authors assume that the only cost of entrepreneurship is effort. From the paper:
We assume that workers can simultaneously work as entrepreneurs (so that there is no occupational choice). This implies that each individual receives wage income in addition to income from entrepreneurship[.]
In other words, the authors have assumed away much of the risk of entrepreneurship! A failed entrepreneur gets paid exactly the same wage income as a worker who doesn't try to be an entrepreneur at all! This automatic wage income reduces the risk of entrepreneurship substantially, and makes social insurance much less necessary for reducing risk.
How realistic is that assumption? Well, in the real world, entrepreneurs in rich countries have limited liability, and can pay themselves wages out of their start-up capital. This means that many entrepreneurs can earn a wage even as they work to start businesses. But this wage is often much less than they could have earned otherwise, and if their business fails (a statistically likely event), they will be unemployed. So the "no occupational choice" assumption probably reduces the risk of entrepreneurship, relative to the real world.
Also, the authors assume that entrepreneurs do not put up any of their own wealth as startup capital for their ventures, and they assume no heterogeneity between worker/entrepreneurs. This means that it is just as easy - and no more risky - for a poor person to start a successful company as for a rich person to do so.
So to sum up my second point, Acemoglu, Robinson, and Verdier have assumed a model in which:
Entrepreneurship is low-risk,
Rich people have no advantage over poor people when it comes to starting companies, and
Your probability of success depends entirely on how hard you work.
(No wonder liberals were not happy about this model, eh?)
So to combine my two points: When it comes to this kind of modeling, what you get out is pretty much what you put in. If you start off with the intuition that success is a function of how hard you work, and how hard you work is a function of how much the government will let you keep your hard-earned gains - in other words, if you start off with the intuition of pretty much every middle-aged conservative guy in America - then your model will probably spit out the result that countries face a tradeoff between redistribution and innovation...again, fitting perfectly with the intuition of pretty much every middle-aged conservative guy in America.
So the model is not counterintuitive. But is it a good model? Does it help us understand the world? Here we have to turn to the data. The data tell us that America issues more patents than Scandinavian countries. Is that good enough? Even if patents are a good measure of innovation (i.e., if Matt Yglesias is wrong), and even if cross-country comparisons are valid, and even if such a small sample were enough to make a statistical inference, I'd still say we have a problem here. Why? Because Acemoglu, Robinson, and Verdier were almost certainly aware of the patents data before they wrote their paper. It is quite probable that the patenting disparity between the U.S. and Scandinavia is what inspired their paper. And one cardinal rule of scientific theorizing is that your model should be tested on data other than the data used to construct the model.
In other words, Acemoglu et al. have not yet succeeded in explaining anything about the world. They have looked at the world, and then used plausible sounding assumptions to create a model whose results fit what they observed. But they have not yet tested whether that model can be used to predict things other than the original observation. Until they do that (or someone else does it), their theory should not be believed.
Anyway, I think I'm done talking about this paper. I am NOT trying to say that Acemoglu and Robinson are wrong, or that they have made any mistakes in their research. What I am trying to do is to illustrate the usefulness of blogs. Even if I've made some mistakes about the particulars (and I may have!), I hope I've shown that blogs, while not a substitute for academic research, do have something to contribute to the academic discussion - by pointing out assumptions, identifying relationships between assumptions and conclusions, discussing alternative assumptions, and evaluating the current status of the research. This is much more than just "distilling well-understood and broadly-accepted notions", which Acemoglu and Robinson claim to be the purpose of blogging.
Update: Some people apparently have been thinking that I'm accusing Acemoglu et al. of political bias. I am doing no such thing. Acemoglu et al. almost certainly just want to demonstrate a neat idea they had (the "asymmetric equilibrium" between "cutthroat" and "cuddly" countries). Demonstrating that, though, requires a model whose assumptions are bound not to be very pleasing to liberals...although again, that's not necessarily the only reason that liberal bloggers criticized the paper. In econ, a lot of accusations and counter-accusations of political bias are always flying around, but I like to keep those to a minimum.
I have a feeling that this sort of paper is the kind of thing the people who insist to me that "Economics is not a science" are pointing at. In this case, it's hard to have too much of a problem with that statement.
Two Things:
1. Did you time this to come out the same day as Yglesias post on innovation?
2. My dad's an entrepreneur, who somehow made it through 2008 only to recently wind down his operations. I gotta say I’m partial to the Scandinavian model. I think knowing his family would be taken care of (education, healthcare, etc.) were he to fail probably would’ve allowed him to take more calculated risk, not to mention unburdened him from an immense amount of psychological pressure.